Sanctioning change: Macrory widens the regulatory toolbox
Howard Fidderman looks at potential changes to sanctions for health and safety breaches.
In November 2006, Professor Richard Macrory published his final report on improving the system of sanctions that are imposed on employers that break the law. The review looked at sanctions available to 60 national regulators, including the HSE, as well as local authorities and fire authorities. Chancellor of the Exchequer Gordon Brown has accepted all the recommendations1, many of which could have an impact on health and safety at work. The HSE, however, appears relaxed with the recommendations, pointing out that their use is discretionary and without a timetable, and that the Better Regulation Executive must, in any case, first include enabling powers in a bill.
The government set the terms for the review in September 2005, in the wake of Philip Hampton's report on the enforcement of business-related legislation (Hampton and the regulators). Ministers asked Macrory, a professor of law, to establish general principles for the use of penalties in the enforcement of regulation and to look at issues such as effective deterrence, eliminating economic benefits of non-compliance, and the use of administrative penalties and alternative sanctions. Public consultation on his proposals (Sanctioning change) closed in August 2006 and has resulted in few significant changes.
REALISING HAMPTON
The Hampton review found that the penalties handed down by courts "are not seen as an adequate deterrent to regulatory non-compliance as the level of financial penalty can often fail to reflect the financial gain of non-compliance with regulatory obligations". Further, the range of enforcement tools is "limited, giving rise to disproportionate use of criminal sanctions, which can be a costly, time-consuming and slow process".
Hampton set out regulatory principles, one of which stated that: "The few businesses that persistently break regulations should be identified quickly and face proportionate and meaningful sanctions." The Macrory review aims to realise this principle by expanding the regulators' and courts' toolbox, making it more flexible, thereby "ensuring that a level playing field is created for all businesses because there is no financial gain from failing to comply. In such a risk-based system, most breaches will face penalties that are quicker and easier to apply, while there will be tougher penalties for rogue businesses which persistently break the rules." As a result, Macrory believes that compliance should improve.
The point of sanctions
While Macrory - like
Nevertheless, Macrory finds a "heavy reliance" on criminal sanctions for regulatory non-compliance. Too heavy a reliance can, he argues, be ineffective because such sanctions:
Not a fine deterrent
Nor do the levels of the fines, in some instances, reflect the financial gains from non-compliance to the offender or the harm suffered by society. This, claims Macrory, means "that these penalties do not act as a deterrent and, in effect, give businesses an incentive to continue to fail to comply in return for a profit". Moreover: "These apparently low financial penalties could be seen as an acceptable risk by businesses that have chosen to be deliberately non-compliant. In these instances it might be assumed that financial penalties in the current system are failing to achieve even the most basic objectives of an effective sanctioning regime."
Macrory notes that the deterrent effect of the £6,855 average fine for a health and safety offence in 2005 "is likely to be limited for all but the smallest businesses"2. But, he adds, large fines "in absolute terms" can be limited in their impact. Specifically, the largest fine imposed for a safety offence - £15 million on Transco - represented just 5% of the company's after-tax profits (HSB 342 p.1): "This shows that even large fines can be absorbed by companies and may not carry the necessary deterrent effect or motivate a change in a firm's behaviour" (although this was not the case with Transco). There is also an issue that magistrates' sentences rarely approach even the current £5,000 and £20,000 maximums.
Impact on regulators
"Without credible and meaningful sanctions," concludes Macrory, "regulators are forced to pursue a more burdensome and bureaucratic enforcement policy. Regulators are deterring non-compliance through their inspection activities. Effective sanctioning is an important signal in achieving deterrence. If criminal prosecutions sent out a strong signal of deterrence, then regulators would be able to impose less onerous burdens on legitimate business by conducting fewer inspections … currently, legitimate businesses see their unscrupulous competitors cut corners, and gain competitive advantage, without facing serious financial or other consequences."
Criminal prosecutions are, in any case, resource intensive for regulators and businesses. The HSE estimates that 20% of cases are approved for prosecution within three months of an offence, and 80% within one year. Industry and regulators, Macrory believes, "may prefer a timelier and less costly resolution to appropriate cases of regulatory non-compliance as the delay and uncertainty of prosecution is burdensome for both". Regulators, he adds, may decide against pursuing a case because the expected low penalty does not justify the time, effort and resources needed to prosecute.
Macrory concludes that such problems lead to "a compliance deficit", in which "non-compliance exists and is identified but no enforcement action is taken because the appropriate tool is not available to the regulator".
THE NEW TOOLBOX
Macrory's new toolbox envisages:
Macrory emphasises that while he is not prescribing changes to the legal framework or status of current offences, he is recommending that the government "initiate a review of the drafting and formulation of criminal offences relating to regulatory non-compliance". This would encompass the rationale for strict liability or reasonable practicability, as well as differences in the need to prove prior knowledge or intent on the employer's part.
Because Macrory is in effect increasing the powers of the regulators, he attaches six "principles" and seven "characteristics" for the operation of an expanded sanctioning toolkit (see box 2). These are largely the same as those set out at consultation, although he has added one characteristic that recognises respondents' concerns that the principles should be applied flexibly so that they do not result in unintended adverse outcomes. Macrory has also softened his proposed characteristic that regulators follow up "all" enforcement action by replacing "all" with a recognition that random selection might better recognise reality. Although regulators should always consider the principles, they need not always apply all of them: the principles are aims, not absolutes.
There is a danger here of over-egging the pudding: the Better Regulation Commission (BRC) has its own "five principles of good regulation" (proportionality, accountability, consistency, transparency and targeting)3 and Hampton published 10 principles of inspection and enforcement. There are also relevant provisions in the Criminal Justice Act 2003 and a future statutory Regulators' Compliance Code, which is provided for in the Legislative and Regulatory Reform Act 2006. Although Macrory acknowledges the BRC's concern that two further sets of principles and characteristics "risked confusing both regulators and those they regulate", he insists his principles are an extension of the BRC's and that "there is a need to set them out separately".
NEW MAPs
Some non-compliance with regulatory requirements would, argues Macrory, be "generally more effectively dealt with" by the use of fixed or variable monetary administrative penalties (FMAPs and VMAPs) applied directly by a regulator. Many countries use them for regulatory - including health and safety - offences. Their use in the UK, however, has tended to be restricted to civil, rather than criminal, non-compliance; only 15 UK regulators can impose administrative penalties, most of which involve "fixed", small amounts.
Macrory believes that MAPs "can provide an intermediate step between the formal, costly and stigmatising action of criminal prosecution and the more informal means of advice and persuasion to get firms back into compliance. Seven in 10 respondents to the consultative document agreed, with three-quarters supporting Macrory's favoured model of FMAPs and VMAPs backed by an appeal to an independent regulatory tribunal.
FMAPs would be applied directly by "lower levels" of a regulator's staff for low-level, minor or high-volume instances of non-compliance. Although Macrory suggests that an FMAP should vary according to the size of employer (numbers of employees, annual turnover etc), he also recommends that the maximum FMAP should not exceed level five on the Criminal Justice Act 1982 standard scale (currently £5,000). Macrory cites their use for health and safety offences in New South Wales, Australia, where they range from £30 to 3,500.
Variable MAPs
Macrory accepts that FMAPs "may not be appropriate for more serious or deliberate cases of regulatory non-compliance or where a firm has made significant financial gains or where the public interest would be best served by a criminal prosecution". In such cases, VMAPs - where the regulator decides the amount in accordance with a published scheme - may be more appropriate, proportionate and for a "more significant amount". The regulator must consider mitigating and aggravating factors (see box 3), the specific circumstances of the offence and the means of the non-compliant business. Other points to note include the following:
There would be no maximum VMAP. Macrory "carefully considered" the issue, particularly a cap of 10% turnover, but concluded that it would "pose undue legal complexity" and could encourage regulators to set VMAPs "at inappropriately high levels".
A senior official within the regulator would decide whether or not to impose a VMAP, following a recommendation by field staff. This would allow consistent application.
The regulator would be allowed to recoup its costs, as in a criminal prosecution (otherwise they would have an incentive to use the criminal scheme) and pursue non-payment of a penalty through ordinary civil debt recovery procedures.
Appeals would be heard by a regulatory tribunal, which would either be a bespoke tribunal or part of the government's proposed First-tier Tribunal.
Employers should be "insulated from the risk of double jeopardy" of facing a VMAP and a private prosecution, although Macrory accepts that the right to the latter "as a matter of general policy … can be a valuable check on regulator behaviour". He recommends only that the government consider the issue when designing the scheme.
Opposition to MAPs
The use of MAPs has met with some opposition. The CBI, for example, fears they might become a "cost of doing business" for the deliberately non-compliant firm, and that inspectors will use them in similar fashion to parking tickets, thereby "fundamentally" changing the relationship between regulators and employers. The British Retail Consortium believes they will result in "tick-box inspections" that would lead to on-the-spot-fines for failures that are currently addressed with advice (or ignored). Rogue traders, the BRC argues, are more likely to be compliant with the threat of court action. Macrory, insists, however, that these fears do not outweigh the advantages and that his proposals, in any case, have sufficient built-in safeguards.
NON-FINANCIAL ALTERNATIVES
Fines and MAPs aside, there will be instances where a financial penalty is inappropriate because: it is insufficient; offenders may pass the cost on to shareholders, employees or customers; it may discriminate against smaller companies; it might not result in the best outcomes in terms of the harm caused; and it can lack a rehabilitation effect (within the business). Macrory therefore recommends four tools that are not instigated by courts: statutory notices, enforceable undertakings, undertakings plus and restorative justice.
Statutory notices
Statutory notices require a recipient to do, or refrain from doing, something, specifying steps to compliance and a timescale. Macrory's recommendation of their use should have little impact on health and safety, beyond the addition of remediation measures, where improvement and prohibition notices are already used. Although failure to comply is met with further sanction, Macrory recommends giving the regulator the option of using a MAP. Regulators should ensure they check on compliance, using a risk-adjusted basis with an element of randomised follow-up.
Macrory also recommends that the government consider whether appeals against all notices should be heard in the new regulatory tribunal rather than magistrates' courts (although appeals against health and safety notices are heard in employment tribunals).
Enforceable undertakings
Enforceable undertakings (EUs) are legally binding agreements between a regulator and an employer, under which the latter will carry out specific activities to rectify its non-compliance. EUs can include provisions for compensation, reimbursement or redress to affected parties. They may also require the offender to carry out a service to the community, such as funding or implementing a compliance education programme. EUs could also be combined with financial administrative sanctions as Undertakings Plus, which might be appropriate where there has been a clear financial gain from non-compliance.
The circumstances in which Macrory envisages the use of EUs are confused. At one stage, he advocates EUs where the regulator has the evidence to take a criminal prosecution or impose a MAP, but the business has "committed to address the issues surrounding the regulatory non-compliance through an EU". Elsewhere, he notes that regulators have limited sanctions for cases that are insufficiently serious to be prosecuted and too serious to receive just an informal warning, and proposes EUs for "instances where a non-financial intermediate sanction may be more suitable".
He then adds that EUs might be effective where a business can "absorb" a financial penalty or criminal conviction, with a limited impact on the culture or management of the firm. EUs, he argues, are likely to be more effective in securing a change in businesses' behaviour compared with other persuasive tools available to regulators. With warning letters and notices, the regulator sets out what needs to be done, and there is no business "buy-in". But businesses would have to apply for an EU, devise their own conditions and "take ownership of the regulatory solution presented".
Evidence from Australia indicates that EUs can offer a quicker and more cost-effective mechanism than court proceedings. Australian businesses said EUs were a "nice way" of warning and offering "another chance", and they encourage candour and promote compliance. Overall, Macrory believes EUs offer regulators flexibility and "represent a powerful alternative to traditional coercive, regulatory enforcement action, and have the potential of imposing fit-for-purpose sanctions which are more satisfying for both offender and the victims of non-compliance".
Restorative justice
Restorative justice (RJ), says Macrory, "is a process whereby those most directly affected by a wrongdoing come together to determine what needs to be done to repair the harm and prevent a reoccurrence". It is a philosophy that views harm and crime as violations of people and of relationships. Compared with the current system of retributive justice, it requires a "paradigm shift" in thinking about responses to harm. "It is justice that puts energy into the future, not into what is past. It focuses on what needs to be restored or repaid and what needs to be learned and strengthened in order for the harm not to reoccur."
Macrory is attracted to RJ because it offers good long-term outcomes for victims and offenders. Studies indicate that victims are more satisfied with RJ than with a court-based process and that the chances of reoffending are reduced. Potential uses include as a pre-court diversion, instead of a MAP, and within the criminal justice system as a pre- and post-sentencing option. RJ is, however, a sensitive area for offender and victim, and Macrory recommends that the government take a gradual approach to RJ with pilot projects.
Responses to the consultative document were encouraging, with three in four supporting the use of RJ. The HSC believes that, used in conjunction with other enforcement tools, RJ may provide "a good framework to match the breach proportionately, and involve and meet the needs of victims, for example rehabilitation, retraining workers, reassurance and support, closure and public support. "RJ would," adds the HSC, "enable an organisation to do the right thing quickly [and] … may well result in improvements in health and safety outcomes in businesses as well as educate the organisation and managers."
CRIMINAL COURTS
All the above recommendations have in common the notion that they avoid, at least in the first instance, a role for the criminal court. Macrory emphasises, however, that the use of criminal prosecutions remains "appropriate for serious breaches where there was evidence of intentional or reckless or repeated flouting of the law". Further, regulators should have discretion to institute criminal proceedings "where there is evidence of gross negligence and/or where the actual or potential consequences of the breach are so serious (such as a death or serious injury) that the public interest demands a criminal prosecution". In such cases, courts should be equipped to impose appropriate sanctions. He therefore recommends:
changes to improve the ability of courts to sentence criminal cases appropriately; and
offering courts five alternative and supplementary sanctions to fines.
Fit-for-purpose courts
In terms of the first group of changes, Macrory believes it would be "sensible" to consolidate certain types of regulatory non-compliance in a particular geographical area. For example, health and safety prosecutions for Greater London are currently initiated in the City of London Magistrates' Court. This could be extended so that particular magistrates courts handle different types of offences.
Macrory also recommends that:
the government invite the Sentencing Guidelines Council to produce guidelines for cases of regulatory non-compliance;
prosecutors ensure that magistrates are aware of the significance of the regulatory regime, the financial benefits of non-compliance and financial circumstances (although magistrates claim that some regulators are remiss, the HSE instructs its inspectors to do precisely this); and
regulators discuss training provision with the Judicial Studies Board, which is responsible for judicial training. Although Macrory rejects - on the grounds of time and resources - training all 28,000 magistrates in England and Wales in regulatory non-compliance, he believes that more systematic training should be available to district judges, prosecutors and justices' clerks (who advise magistrates), as well as to courts that hear particular types of offence.
Alternative sanctions
Courts will only be fit-for-purpose, however, once they are able to impose appropriate sanctions. While their powers remain restricted to fines for most regulatory breaches, this will not be the case. To this end, Macrory recommends the government consider introducing five alternative and supplementary types of sanction:profits orders; corporate rehabilitation orders; community projects; mandatory compliance audits; and publicity orders.
Profits orders
While fines should take into account any savings made by non-compliance, Macrory believes that in cases where savings are "clear" - for example, a failure to pay a licence fee - it would be preferable if criminal courts had the power to impose a profits order, which would be separate from a fine. Macrory believes this will help create a transparency and a level playing field.
The order would be a non-judgmental sanction restricted to the direct financial benefits of non-compliance as well as deferred costs, whereas the fine would represent the court's assessment of the gravity of the breach. For example, the fine might be small if the employer had been careless rather than reckless, but the profit order might be significant if the savings were large. The prosecution would apply for the order.
Corporate rehabilitation orders
Corporate rehabilitation orders (CROs) allow criminal courts to impose a sanction similar to enforceable undertakings. Following conviction, an offender can propose a plan of action to remedy the matter that caused the harm. Macrory suggests this could include a community project or compliance audit. The court can approve the plan or appoint its own experts to design a more robust plan. The regulator would monitor subsequent compliance; failure to comply would result in an alternative sentence. An order will often replace a fine, but Macrory suggests courts can use both together.
Community projects
Macrory is not prescriptive about CROs, suggesting they could include community improvement projects with a value that is related to that of the harm, for example funding and delivering an education campaign or a public park. Projects might be particularly appropriate where the offender does not have the ability to pay a large financial penalty. The task should be additional to anything the company is already legally obliged to do and the offender should not be allowed to use the project for public relations purposes. The experience of Australia, where community projects are used for health and safety offences, has been positive, with tangible benefits to the local community and greater engagement of the business.
Mandatory compliance audits
Also common in Australia - in state environmental regulation - the power to compel an organisation to undertake an audit is used to remedy deficiencies in business management. Macrory believes that these mandatory compliance audits may be appropriate where systematic organisational change would help achieve future compliance.
He envisages UK criminal courts ordering an audit, which must be carried out by an accredited third party. The audit would identify the changes that a business needs to make to protect the public and also to provide a framework to ensure the changes are made. The audit would be systematic, documented and objective and look at the employer's facilities, operations and products. A court could order an audit in addition to, or in place of, another sentence, and it could direct the regulator to monitor the compliance.
Publicity orders
Macrory believes that "reputational sanctions can have more of an impact than even the largest financial penalties" in motivating firms to change their behaviour. He suggests that courts could make a publicity order for a notice - with the wording agreed between the offender and the regulator - to appear in "an appropriate publication". This could be a local or national newspaper, a trade journal, or on radio or television. The wording would cover the background to the offence, the steps taken by the offender to avoid repetition, and remedial and compensatory measures.
"Publicity orders", claims Macrory, "can make a business's behaviour more public and really hold it to account": a company that loses its reputation "even for a short time can suffer significant damage to consumer confidence, market share and equity value". The CBI, for example, told Macrory that the HSE's "name and shame" database "puts peer pressure on those firms that have issues to address and threatens adverse impact on their reputation". The order would, however, differ from the HSE's database in that it would be imposed by a criminal court. It can be in addition to, or in place of, another sentence.
THE LIMITS OF DISCRETION
As we noted at consultation stage, there is much to welcome in Macrory's report: the use of profit orders, higher and more appropriate fines and alternative sanctions all have the potential to increase health and safety compliance and contribute to a level playing field. There are, however, uncertainties as to how the recommendations will unravel in practice.
The Macrory report - and the preceding consultation document - applies to 60 regulators and, as such, gives few explicit indications as to what the recommendations might mean for individual regulators. Nevertheless, the HSE appears relaxed about the implications of the report, insisting that it will not impose significant changes on the HSE or on the "way it works" and that it "poses no threat" to the HSC's enforcement strategy" 4.
Given this, the HSE can "welcome" the set of penalties and the framework for their application: "The use of criminal prosecutions would remain appropriate for serious breaches where there was evidence of intentional or reckless flouting of the law, whether by an individual or a business. How current regulatory tools are used and applied would not be affected." Further, the HSE envisages that "there will be no compulsion on the [HSE] to adopt any new alternative penalty proposed. The intention is to allow the regulator to choose, if any, the best-fit alternative penalty tool(s) for [its] regime. Any alternative penalty would need to be in addition, and not an alternative, to existing powers."
The HSE has not indicated which alternative powers it might cherry pick, although there may be some clues in its own online consultation (HSB 345 p.16). While this revealed support for alternative penalties in principle, only administrative fines and adverse publicity orders attracted broad support when consultees were asked about specific alternatives.
Having it both ways
Still less certain is whether the HSE is safe in its complacency. Macrory wants to have it both ways: on the one hand, he talks about leaving regulators to make up their own minds about his recommendations; on the other, he claims that his recommendations "will bring a paradigm shift to the way in which regulatory sanctions are designed and used, making them more flexible and encouraging compliance". So while the HSE believes that it will be able to use existing criminal sanctions for offences that it currently prosecutes, Macrory argues that "most breaches [of all, not just health and safety, requirements] will face penalties that are quicker and easier to apply" and that MAPs will be used for a sizeable proportion of regulatory offences.
As we noted earlier, Macrory also argues that criminal prosecutions would continue to be appropriate for serious breaches. These would include those that were intentional, reckless or repeated. But he also would allow "discretion" in cases that involved gross negligence, injury or death. Then, to add to the confusion, he acknowledges that "it is reasonable to assume that [current prosecutions] are for the most serious offences and offenders."
And indeed, nearly all of the HSE's prosecutions follow serious compliance failures; most of them involve injuries. The HSE has more often been criticised over the years for failing to prosecute a sufficient number of incidents that have led to major injuries, rather than for over-prosecuting. If serious offences are to continue to be remedied appropriately - ie in the criminal courts - which "lesser" health and safety failures will attract administrative penalties other than those that are currently remedied with a quiet word in the employer's ear?
1 "Regulatory justice: making sanctions effective. Final report", Richard Macrory, November 2006, www.cabinetoffice.gov.uk/regulation/reviewing_regulation/penalties/index.asp.
2 Adjusted to exclude "exceptional" fines of £100,000 or more. Macrory attributes the average of £6,855 to magistrates only. In fact, it includes Crown Court fines - which are usually higher - making the situation worse than even Macrory describes.
3 www.brc.gov.uk/publications/principlesentry.asp.
4 "BRE - Macrory penalties review consultation document: regulatory justice - sanctioning in a post-Hampton world", HSC/06/30, www.hse.gov.uk/aboutus/hsc/meetings/2006index.htm.
Howard Fidderman is editor of HSB.
Criminal court sanctions Improve the effectiveness of criminal courts for cases of regulatory non-compliance.
Introduce alternative sanctioning options for cases of regulatory non-compliance heard in the criminal courts, including profits orders, corporate rehabilitation orders, community projects, mandatory compliance audits and publicity orders.
Regulators' sanctions Introduce fixed and variable monetary administrative penalties, with appeals heard through an independent regulatory tribunal.
Strengthen and extend the system of statutory notices.
Introduce enforceable undertakings and undertakings plus.
Introduce pilot restorative justice projects.
|